版權(quán)說明:本文檔由用戶提供并上傳,收益歸屬內(nèi)容提供方,若內(nèi)容存在侵權(quán),請進(jìn)行舉報(bào)或認(rèn)領(lǐng)
文檔簡介
1、<p> 中文3608字,2170單詞,1.2萬英文字符</p><p> 本科畢業(yè)論文外文翻譯</p><p> 外文題目:Determinants of Intra-Industry Trade Between Developing </p><p> Countries and the United States
2、 </p><p> 出 處:Journal of Economic Development </p><p> 作 者:Don P. Clark and Denise L. Stanley </p><p><b> 譯 文:<
3、/b></p><p> 發(fā)展中國家和美國之間產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易的決定因素</p><p> Helpman and Krugman (1985)研究國家特征確定南北模型的產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易。這些地區(qū)之間最重要的區(qū)別在于在他們的相對要素稟賦。北方是資本相對豐富,南是勞動(dòng)力相對豐富。在生產(chǎn)規(guī)模收益遞增的競爭激烈市場和具有恒定報(bào)酬比例的同質(zhì)勞動(dòng)密集型產(chǎn)品上的條件下,每個(gè)區(qū)域生產(chǎn)一種差異化、資本相對密
4、集的制成品。這兩個(gè)地區(qū)消費(fèi)者的需求呈現(xiàn)多樣化。南部出口勞動(dòng)密集型產(chǎn)品。這兩個(gè)地區(qū)生產(chǎn)和出口各種不同的產(chǎn)品,但是北部是制成品的凈出口國。在這里,在資本密集型的差異化產(chǎn)品報(bào)酬遞增產(chǎn)業(yè)間貿(mào)易規(guī)模報(bào)酬與勞動(dòng)共存密集產(chǎn)品而產(chǎn)生的產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易是由國家間的不同而造成的。</p><p> Helpman and Krugman (1985)證明了產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易取決于貿(mào)易國雙方的相對要素稟賦和經(jīng)濟(jì)規(guī)模。生產(chǎn)要素的均衡再分配,使得南北
5、或多或少的在經(jīng)濟(jì)規(guī)模上的不相等,顯示出產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易總量的減少(增加)。當(dāng)要素再分配不改變南北方的相對大小,反而增加(減少)相對要素稟賦的不平等性,產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易總量將減少(增加)。因此,產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易會因?yàn)槟媳彪p方相對要素稟賦差異和經(jīng)濟(jì)規(guī)模的擴(kuò)大(縮?。┒鴾p少(增加)。</p><p> Flam and Helpman(1987),Falvey and Kierzkowski(1987),and Falvey(1981
6、)調(diào)查南北產(chǎn)業(yè)水平的決定因素。產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易被看作是一個(gè)基于質(zhì)量差異的垂直產(chǎn)品差異化而不是規(guī)模經(jīng)濟(jì)或水平產(chǎn)品差異化的結(jié)果。每個(gè)行業(yè)包括了區(qū)別在質(zhì)量上的各種各樣的產(chǎn)品。不同的勞動(dòng)生產(chǎn)率和/或要素稟賦所體現(xiàn)出來的技術(shù)決定了生產(chǎn)的質(zhì)量范圍。自給自足均衡是指,北部享有資本密集型的高品質(zhì)的產(chǎn)品的比較優(yōu)勢,而南部專營勞動(dòng)密集型的較低質(zhì)量的產(chǎn)品。產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易的產(chǎn)生是因?yàn)橄M(fèi)者渴望買到與他們的收入水平相一致的產(chǎn)品質(zhì)量,并因?yàn)槊總€(gè)國家生產(chǎn)的品質(zhì)范圍與需要的品質(zhì)
7、范圍不同。由此產(chǎn)生的貿(mào)易模式是北部出口高品質(zhì)的產(chǎn)品,以換取南部較低質(zhì)量的行業(yè)分類相同的產(chǎn)品。</p><p> 南北貿(mào)易模型所用的變量通常用于識別美國和30個(gè)發(fā)展中國家雙邊貿(mào)易中的國家和產(chǎn)業(yè)水平的產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易的決定因素。Helpman and Krugman (1985) 認(rèn)為產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易的份額與橫跨國家間的相對要素稟賦和相對國家大小的差異有關(guān)。國家間相對要素稟賦相差越大,產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易的份額越小。由于貿(mào)易合作伙伴規(guī)模
8、擴(kuò)大,美國和發(fā)展中國家規(guī)模越來越相似。規(guī)模較小的國家將對產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易份額有積極影響。我們期望產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易與要素稟賦的差異呈現(xiàn)負(fù)相關(guān)。</p><p> 貿(mào)易伙伴之間的距離作為交易非標(biāo)準(zhǔn)化產(chǎn)品所必須的一個(gè)信息成本代理。Balassa and Bauwens(1987)認(rèn)為非標(biāo)準(zhǔn)化的產(chǎn)品特性比標(biāo)準(zhǔn)化商品特性需要更多的信息。與標(biāo)準(zhǔn)產(chǎn)品相比,克服距離相關(guān)的摩擦將更多地為了可替換的非標(biāo)準(zhǔn)產(chǎn)品而相應(yīng)地阻止貿(mào)易。產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易將被消
9、極地與美國及其一個(gè)貿(mào)易伙伴之間的距離聯(lián)系起來。</p><p> 一個(gè)發(fā)展中國家的貿(mào)易方向也將影響產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易。Falvey(1981)的模型顯示了有更少貿(mào)易壁壘的國家,將有較高水平的產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易。沿著Stone and Lee(1995),Balassa and Bauwens(1987),Balassa(1986)的研究,貿(mào)易方向是以基于人均所得和人口數(shù)量上的人均貿(mào)易(出口加進(jìn)口)的回歸殘差為代表的。產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易
10、份額將與發(fā)展中國家的貿(mào)易戰(zhàn)略取向(TO)正相關(guān)。</p><p> Grubel and Lloyd(1975)認(rèn)為對產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易的測量會受到一個(gè)國家貿(mào)易平衡與否的影響。這種影響會更加擴(kuò)大凈貿(mào)易所占份額,使產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易所占份額變小。該指數(shù)應(yīng)該與貿(mào)易不平衡負(fù)相關(guān),所以如果貿(mào)易不平衡是與解釋性變量相關(guān),估計(jì)回歸方程系數(shù)會出現(xiàn)偏差。根據(jù)Stone and Lee(1995),我們包含了一個(gè)不平衡的貿(mào)易措施來控制這個(gè)可能出
11、現(xiàn)的偏差。產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易被期望與貿(mào)易不平衡負(fù)相關(guān)。</p><p> 各種產(chǎn)業(yè)水平的特征也被看作對南北模型的產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易有影響。產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易的范圍不但會被產(chǎn)品標(biāo)準(zhǔn)化和差異化程度所影響,也會被全球的生產(chǎn)過程的綜合性質(zhì)所影響。</p><p> Balassa(1986),Greenaway and Milner(1986)認(rèn)為,廠級規(guī)模經(jīng)濟(jì)出現(xiàn)在那些由于縮小工廠規(guī)模而降低成本的生產(chǎn)標(biāo)準(zhǔn)化產(chǎn)品的產(chǎn)
12、業(yè)中。這種橫向?qū)I(yè)化導(dǎo)致的結(jié)果是標(biāo)準(zhǔn)化的產(chǎn)品與產(chǎn)業(yè)間貿(mào)易聯(lián)系起來。垂直專業(yè)化使零件、部件、配件以及最終產(chǎn)品在不同的工廠進(jìn)行生產(chǎn)。運(yùn)營操作被細(xì)分到許多工廠之后,工廠的規(guī)模是減小而不是增大。垂直專業(yè)化導(dǎo)致非標(biāo)準(zhǔn)化的產(chǎn)品和產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易的發(fā)生。如最低效率規(guī)模一樣,廠級規(guī)模經(jīng)濟(jì)的傳統(tǒng)測量方法是與產(chǎn)品的標(biāo)準(zhǔn)化程度正相關(guān)。最低效率規(guī)模是長期平均成本達(dá)到其最低水平時(shí)的最小產(chǎn)量。由于最低效率規(guī)模反映了產(chǎn)品的標(biāo)準(zhǔn)化程度,非標(biāo)準(zhǔn)化的產(chǎn)品與產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易有關(guān),南北模
13、型的產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易份額與最低效率規(guī)模預(yù)計(jì)呈負(fù)相關(guān)。</p><p> 有三個(gè)因素充當(dāng)著產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)專業(yè)化分工潛在收益的額外代表。產(chǎn)品的標(biāo)準(zhǔn)化也關(guān)系到賣方集中程度和行業(yè)單位數(shù)目。Balassa(1986)認(rèn)為當(dāng)賣方的集中程度變大時(shí),一個(gè)行業(yè)的差異化產(chǎn)品生產(chǎn)將減少。擁有許多公司的行業(yè)會生產(chǎn)大量的差異化產(chǎn)品。賣方四企業(yè)表示濃度表示四個(gè)最大的公司在1992年的裝運(yùn)值的比重。產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易與賣方四企業(yè)集中度(CR4)預(yù)計(jì)呈負(fù)相關(guān),與機(jī)
14、構(gòu)單位數(shù)目呈正相關(guān)。</p><p> 部門分散指數(shù),作為一個(gè)從產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)獲得潛在收益的專業(yè)化代理,它反映了產(chǎn)業(yè)消費(fèi)者的多樣化。該指數(shù)的下限值是與行業(yè)服務(wù)于很可能使用定做產(chǎn)品的廣大消費(fèi)者各種產(chǎn)業(yè)。產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易預(yù)計(jì)將部門分散指數(shù)(DSPH)呈負(fù)相關(guān)。</p><p> 南北貿(mào)易模式視產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易為一個(gè)基于不同質(zhì)量而導(dǎo)致垂直產(chǎn)品差異的結(jié)果。根據(jù)同一行業(yè)的分類,北部向南部出口高質(zhì)量產(chǎn)品換取低質(zhì)量的產(chǎn)
15、品下降了。垂直產(chǎn)品差異被代理為1987年的廣告對銷售的比率,廣告意在區(qū)分產(chǎn)品,利用質(zhì)量的不同,轉(zhuǎn)移需求函數(shù),或者改變價(jià)格需求彈性。建立在產(chǎn)品質(zhì)量不同上的垂直產(chǎn)品差異的范圍將在高廣告強(qiáng)度的工業(yè)中更廣泛。預(yù)計(jì)南北產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易模式更會被積極的聯(lián)系到廣告銷售率上。</p><p> 影響南北產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易的兩個(gè)變量涉及到生產(chǎn)過程的性質(zhì)。其中的第一個(gè)是由測資本與勞動(dòng)的比例測量的生產(chǎn)的資本密集度。北部出口優(yōu)質(zhì)資本密集型產(chǎn)品去交換
16、南部屬于同一行業(yè)分類的低質(zhì)量勞動(dòng)密集型產(chǎn)品。要素密集度會影響生產(chǎn)的品質(zhì)。勞動(dòng)力越密集,低勞動(dòng)力成本國家生產(chǎn)產(chǎn)品的規(guī)模越大。產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易預(yù)計(jì)與資本與勞動(dòng)的比值呈負(fù)相關(guān)。</p><p> Balassa(1986)認(rèn)為海上裝配條款鼓勵(lì)垂直產(chǎn)品專業(yè)化。工業(yè)與垂直整合的生產(chǎn)過程可以使用海上裝配條款按照合理化與比較優(yōu)勢格局生產(chǎn)。將要出口美國行業(yè)高、中級技術(shù)產(chǎn)品和部件,進(jìn)口技術(shù)含量低的勞動(dòng)密集型產(chǎn)品和組件。海上裝配條款是衡
17、量1992年的進(jìn)口總額中的海上裝配條款進(jìn)口份額。產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易的份額將與海上裝配條款的活性呈正相關(guān)。</p><p> 最后一個(gè)變量包含在代理分類匯總。一些研究認(rèn)為,當(dāng)更好層次的產(chǎn)品集合用于定義產(chǎn)業(yè)時(shí),產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易將減少。這導(dǎo)致了一種預(yù)期認(rèn)為那些由許多產(chǎn)品群組成的大型產(chǎn)業(yè)比由少數(shù)產(chǎn)品群組成的存在更多的產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易。按照Marvel and Ray(1987)的研究,分類聚合是由工業(yè)代理貨物的價(jià)值,承擔(dān)更多聚集在裝運(yùn)價(jià)值
18、較高的行業(yè)。產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易預(yù)計(jì)將積極與工業(yè)的出貨量呈正相關(guān)。國家特點(diǎn)這一概念是來自聯(lián)合國(1997)、經(jīng)濟(jì)學(xué)人(1997)和Fitzpatric and Modlin(1986)。DIFF初始單位為美元。衡量國內(nèi)生產(chǎn)總值所用的單位是百萬美元。距離單位是公里。用于構(gòu)造產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易指數(shù)的進(jìn)出口數(shù)字是從美國統(tǒng)計(jì)局(1993)得來的。進(jìn)口貨值的海上裝配條款是從美國統(tǒng)計(jì)局(1995)得來的。CR4是從美國統(tǒng)計(jì)局(1992)得來的。DSPH和AS計(jì)算是從
19、美國商務(wù)部(1994)得來的。MES、ESTAB、KL和VS是從美國統(tǒng)計(jì)局(1995)得來的。KL是衡量美國百萬美元的產(chǎn)業(yè)每個(gè)工人的資本數(shù)。ESTAB的衡量單位是萬。VS的衡量單位是百萬美元。</p><p> 產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易被發(fā)現(xiàn)隨著越大的南北間相對要素稟賦差異(人均國內(nèi)生產(chǎn)總值)而逐漸減弱。貿(mào)易伙伴的規(guī)模對產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易有積極影響。這些研究結(jié)果和Helpman and Krugman(1985)的理論模型是一致的。
20、距離對產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易有著消極的影響。發(fā)展中國家貿(mào)易的方向?qū)Ξa(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易產(chǎn)生了積極的的影響。</p><p> 南北貿(mào)易理論模型視產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易是建立在保證質(zhì)量基礎(chǔ)上的垂直產(chǎn)品差異化,而不是由于規(guī)模經(jīng)濟(jì)或水平產(chǎn)品差異化問題的后果。一些研究結(jié)果支持這些模型結(jié)論。我們在產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易和廣告強(qiáng)度之間發(fā)現(xiàn)的一個(gè)積極關(guān)系支持了垂直產(chǎn)品差異化的作用。規(guī)模經(jīng)濟(jì)并沒有被發(fā)現(xiàn)在產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易程度上發(fā)揮決定作用。這可能是由于這樣的事實(shí):技術(shù)含量不高產(chǎn)
21、品聚集在發(fā)展中國家都不容易使用自動(dòng)化大規(guī)模生產(chǎn)設(shè)備。一個(gè)產(chǎn)業(yè)的要素集中程度會影響生產(chǎn)品質(zhì)的范圍。當(dāng)貨物可由勞動(dòng)密集型行業(yè)的生產(chǎn)技術(shù)進(jìn)行生產(chǎn)時(shí),垂直產(chǎn)品差異化的范圍將擴(kuò)大。我們在南北產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易和產(chǎn)業(yè)資本勞動(dòng)力比率中找到一個(gè)消極的關(guān)系。北部出口優(yōu)質(zhì)資本密集型產(chǎn)品去交換南部屬于同一行業(yè)分類的低質(zhì)量勞動(dòng)密集型產(chǎn)品。海上裝配條款的使用,我們的產(chǎn)業(yè)代表全球一體化的特點(diǎn),這樣就對產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易程度產(chǎn)生了積極的影響。這一發(fā)現(xiàn)也適用于垂直產(chǎn)品差異化對產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)
22、易的決定作用。美國產(chǎn)業(yè)從事生產(chǎn)共享操作傾向于出口高、中級技術(shù),進(jìn)口產(chǎn)品和組件的勞動(dòng)密集型產(chǎn)品和低技術(shù)含量的部件。</p><p> 美國和發(fā)展中國家之間相當(dāng)份額的制成品貿(mào)易組成了產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易。貿(mào)易自由化會繼續(xù)增大產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易份額在貿(mào)易總額的比率。當(dāng)兩個(gè)國家在相對要素稟賦與經(jīng)濟(jì)規(guī)模變得更相似時(shí),產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易會更強(qiáng)大。更多的產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易會發(fā)生在垂直分化、非標(biāo)準(zhǔn)和全球一體化的大產(chǎn)業(yè)所生產(chǎn)的定做產(chǎn)品。南北貿(mào)易理論和實(shí)證模型應(yīng)該
23、關(guān)注那些南北之間的與國家特點(diǎn)、基于質(zhì)量差異的垂直產(chǎn)品差異化、產(chǎn)品標(biāo)準(zhǔn)化程度和勞動(dòng)成本相關(guān)的產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易來源。</p><p> Determinants of Intra-Industry Trade Between Developing Countries and the United States</p><p> Don P. Clark and Deni
24、se L. Stanley</p><p> Helpman and Krugman (1985) explore the role of country characteristics in determining North-South IIT. The most important difference between these regions lies in their relat
25、ive factor endowments. The North is relatively capital abundant and the South is labor abundant. Each region produces a differentiated, relatively capital-intensive manufactured good under conditions of increa
26、sing returns to scale in a monopolistically competitive market, and a homogeneous labor-</p><p> Helpman and Krugman (1985) demonstrate the volume of IIT depends on both</p><
27、p> relative factor endowments and economic size of trading nations. A proportional reallocation of productive factors that makes the North and South more (less) unequal in economic size is shown to re
28、duce (increase) the volume of IIT. When a reallocation of factors does not alter the relative size of the North and South, but increases (decreases) the disparity in relative factor endowments, the volume of II
29、T will decrease (increase). Thus, IIT will tend to decrease (inc</p><p> Flam and Helpman (1987), Falvey and Kierzkowski (1987), and Falvey (1981)</p><p> examine industry-level d
30、eterminants of North-South trade. IIT is viewed as a consequence of vertical product differentiation based on quality differences, rather than as a result of scale economies or horizontal product different
31、iation. Each industry is defined to include a variety of products differing in quality. Technology reflected in labor productivity differences and/or factor endowments determines the range of qualities produced. The
32、 autarky equilibrium is one in which</p><p> Variables suggested by models of North-South trade are used to identify country and industry-level determinants of IIT in bilateral trade between the U.S. and
33、 30 developing countries. Helpman and Krugman (1985) relate the share of IIT to cross-country differences in relative factor endowments and relative country size. The more countries differ in relative factor en
34、dowments, the smaller the share of IIT. As the size of the trading partner grows, the U.S. and a developing c</p><p> Distance between trading partners serves as a proxy for costs of information n
35、ecessary for trading nonstandardized products. Balassa and Bauwens (1987) argue more information is required on characteristics of nonstandardized products than on character- istics of standardized goods. Frictions ass
36、ociated with overcoming distance will deter trade proportionately more for closely substitutable nonstandardized products than for standardized goods.8 IIT should be negatively correlated with</p><p&
37、gt; Trade orientation of a developing country will also influence IIT. Falvey’s (1981) model shows countries with lower trade barriers will have higher levels of IIT. Following Stone and Lee (1995), Balassa and Bau
38、wens (1987), and Balassa (1986), trade orientation is proxied by the residuals from a regression of per capita trade (exports plus imports) on per capita income and population. The share of IIT will b
39、e positively correlated with the developing country’s trade</p><p> Grubel and Lloyd (1975) note their measure of IIT will be affected by the trade imbalance of a country. This effect wi
40、ll be greater the larger the share of net trade and the smaller the share of IIT in total trade. The index should be negatively correlated with the trade imbalance so estimated coefficients in th
41、e regression equation will be biased if the trade imbalance is correlated with the explanatory variables. Following Stone and Lee (1</p><p> According to Balassa (1986) and Greenaway and Mil
42、ner (1986), plant-level scale economies are captured in industries producing standardized products whose costs decline with increases in plant size. This horizontal specialization results in standardized products tha
43、t are associated with inter-industry trade. Vertical specialization entails producing parts, components, accessories, and the final product in different plants. Plant size is decreased rather than increased as operat
44、ions are su</p><p> Three factors serve as additional proxies for potential gains from intraindustry specialization. Product standardization is also related to the extent of seller concentrat
45、ion and the number of establishments in an industry. Balassa (1986) argues the number of differentiated products produced in an industry will decline as seller concentration increases. Industries with many es
46、tablishments will produce a larger number of differentiated products. The four-firm seller con</p><p> The sectoral dispersion index, which reflects the diversity of industry consumers,</p>
47、<p> serves as a proxy for potential gains from intraindustry specialization. Lower values of this index are associated with industries serving a wide variety of industrial consumers who are likel
48、y to do so with made-to-order products. IIT is expected to be negatively correlated with the sectoral dispersion index (DSPH).</p><p> North-South trade models view IIT as a consequence of vertical pr
49、oduct differentiation based on quality differences. The North exports high quality products to the South in exchange for lower quality products falling under the same industry classification. Vertical product differentia
50、tion is proxied by the 1987 advertising-to-sales ratio. Advertising is intended to differentiate products, exploit quality differences, shift the demand function, and/or change the price elasticity of demand for a</
51、p><p> Two variables influencing North-South IIT relate to the nature of the production process. The first of these is the capital intensity of production, measured by the capital-to-labor ratio. North-South I
52、IT involves the North exporting capital intensive high-quality products and components to the South in exchange for labor intensive lower-quality products and components falling under the same industry classification.
53、Factor intensity will influence the range of qualities produced. The </p><p> The globally integrated nature of an industry is proxied by industrial participation</p><p> und
54、er offshore assembly provisions (OAPs) in the U.S. tariff code. OAPs refer to items HTS 9802 of the Tariff Schedule of the United States. HTS tariff item 9802.00.60 (formerly 806.3) allows metal articles to be
55、 imported duty-free into the U.S. except for the value of processing performed abroad. HTS item 9802.00.80 (formerly 807.00) covers imported articles assembled abroad with U.S. - made components. Duties are asses
56、sed on the full value of the item less the value of the U</p><p> Balassa (1986) argues OAPs encourage vertical product specialization. Industries with vertically integrated production processes ca
57、n use OAPs to rationalize production in accordance with the pattern of comparative advantage. A U.S industry will export high and intermediate-technology products and components, and import low-technolog
58、y labor intensive products and components. OAP is measured as the share of OAP imports in total 1992 imports. The share of IIT i</p><p> A final variable is included to proxy categorical aggrega
59、tion. Several studies have argued that IIT should fall when finer levels of product aggregation are used to define industries. This leads to an expectation that large industries comprised of many product groups should h
60、ave more IIT than industries with only a few product groups. Following Marvel and Ray (1987), categorical aggregation is proxied by the value of industry shipments, assuming more aggregation is involved in industri
61、es </p><p> Country characteristics are taken from United Nations (1997), the Economist (1997),</p><p> and Fitzpatric and Modlin (1986). DIFF is measured in U.S. dollars. GDP is
62、 expressed in millions of U.S. dollars. Distance is in kilometers. Export and import figures used to construct the IIT index are from the U.S. Bureau of the Census (1993). The value of OAP import
63、s is from the U.S. Bureau of the Census (1995a). CR4 is from the U.S. Bureau of the Census (1992). DSPH and AS are calculated from the U.S. Department of Commerce (1994). MES, ESTAB, KL, </p><p> I
64、IT is found to fall with greater differences in relative factor endowments (proxied by differences in per capita GDP) between the North and South. Size of the trading partner influences IIT in a positive way. These fin
65、dings are consistent with predictions of Helpman and Krugman’s (1985) theoretical model. Distance influences IIT in a negative way. Trade orientation of the developing country exerts a positive effect on
66、IIT.</p><p> Theoretical models of NS trade view IIT as a consequence of vertical product</p><p> differentiation based on quality differences rather than as a result of
67、 scale economies or horizontal product differentiation. Several findings support conclusions of these models. Our finding of a positive relationship between IIT and advertising intensity supports the role of
68、 vertical product differentiation. Scale economies are not found to play a role in determining the extent of IIT. This could be due to the fact that low-technology products assembled in de</p><p>
69、 A considerable share of trade in manufactured goods between the U.S. and developing countries is found to consist of IIT. As trade liberalization continues the share of IIT in total trade can be expected t
70、o grow. IIT will be greater as countries become more similar both in relative factor endowments and economic size. More IIT will occur in vertically differentiated, nonstandard, made-to-order products prod
溫馨提示
- 1. 本站所有資源如無特殊說明,都需要本地電腦安裝OFFICE2007和PDF閱讀器。圖紙軟件為CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.壓縮文件請下載最新的WinRAR軟件解壓。
- 2. 本站的文檔不包含任何第三方提供的附件圖紙等,如果需要附件,請聯(lián)系上傳者。文件的所有權(quán)益歸上傳用戶所有。
- 3. 本站RAR壓縮包中若帶圖紙,網(wǎng)頁內(nèi)容里面會有圖紙預(yù)覽,若沒有圖紙預(yù)覽就沒有圖紙。
- 4. 未經(jīng)權(quán)益所有人同意不得將文件中的內(nèi)容挪作商業(yè)或盈利用途。
- 5. 眾賞文庫僅提供信息存儲空間,僅對用戶上傳內(nèi)容的表現(xiàn)方式做保護(hù)處理,對用戶上傳分享的文檔內(nèi)容本身不做任何修改或編輯,并不能對任何下載內(nèi)容負(fù)責(zé)。
- 6. 下載文件中如有侵權(quán)或不適當(dāng)內(nèi)容,請與我們聯(lián)系,我們立即糾正。
- 7. 本站不保證下載資源的準(zhǔn)確性、安全性和完整性, 同時(shí)也不承擔(dān)用戶因使用這些下載資源對自己和他人造成任何形式的傷害或損失。
最新文檔
- 發(fā)展中國家和美國之間產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易的決定因素【外文翻譯】
- 外文翻譯--東亞產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易測度與決定因素的研究(節(jié)選)
- 美國產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易的決定因素和研究模式【外文翻譯】
- fdi在發(fā)展中國家的決定因素分析【外文翻譯】
- fdi在發(fā)展中國家的決定因素分析外文翻譯
- 發(fā)展中國家對外直接投資的決定因素【外文翻譯】
- 外文翻譯--發(fā)展中國家對外直接投資的決定因素
- 東亞產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易測度與決定因素的研究【外文翻譯】
- 發(fā)展中國家的匯率決定因素研究
- 分析發(fā)展中國家的外商直接投資決定因素【外文翻譯】
- 外文翻譯--東亞產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易測度與決定因素的研究【原文】
- 外國直接投資在發(fā)展中國家的決定因素分析【外文翻譯】
- 中國產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易決定因素:理論與實(shí)證分析.pdf
- 中國產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易程度及其決定因素的實(shí)證分析.pdf
- 中日產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易的發(fā)展?fàn)顩r及其決定因素研究.pdf
- 中國對發(fā)展中國家OFDI區(qū)位決定因素實(shí)證研究.pdf
- 中國制成品產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易的現(xiàn)狀、決定因素及實(shí)證檢驗(yàn).pdf
- 國際貿(mào)易對發(fā)展中國家的環(huán)境效應(yīng)研究——基于產(chǎn)業(yè)內(nèi)貿(mào)易的視角.pdf
- 經(jīng)濟(jì)金融外文翻譯--- 發(fā)達(dá)國家和發(fā)展中國家的erp實(shí)施問題
- 外文文獻(xiàn)翻譯----發(fā)達(dá)國家和發(fā)展中國家的erp實(shí)施問題
評論
0/150
提交評論