版權(quán)說明:本文檔由用戶提供并上傳,收益歸屬內(nèi)容提供方,若內(nèi)容存在侵權(quán),請(qǐng)進(jìn)行舉報(bào)或認(rèn)領(lǐng)
文檔簡介
1、<p> 2000單詞,1.1萬英文字符,3600漢字</p><p> 本科畢業(yè)論文外文翻譯</p><p> 外文題目: The governance of global value chains </p><p> 出 處: Gereffi G, Humphrey J, Sturgeon T. The Gover
2、nance of Global Value Chain[J]. Review of International Political Economy, 2005, 12(1):78-104. </p><p> 作 者: Gary Gereffi;John Humphrey;Timothy Sturgeon </p><p><b> 原文:</b&
3、gt;</p><p> The Governance of Global Value Chains</p><p><b> ABSTRACT</b></p><p> This article builds a theoretical framework to help explain governance patterns in g
4、lobal value chains. It draws on three streams of literature – transaction costs economics, production networks, and technological capability and firm-level learning– to identify three variables that play a large role in
5、determining how global value chains are governed and change. These are: (1) the complexity of transactions, (2) the ability to codify transactions, and (3) the capabilities in the supply-base. The</p><p> K
6、EYWORDS:Global value chains; governance; networks; transaction costs; value chain modularity</p><p> The world economy has changed in significant ways during the past several decades, especially in the area
7、s of international trade and industrial organization. Two of the most important new features of the contemporary economy are the globalization of production and trade,1 which have fueled the growth of industrial capabili
8、ties in a wide range of developing countries, and the vertical disintegration of transnational corporations, which are redefining their core competencies to focus on innovatio</p><p> The evolution of globa
9、l-scale industrial organization affects not only the fortunes of firms and the structure of industries, but also how and why countries advance — or fail to advance — in the global economy. Global value chain research and
10、 policy work examine the different ways in which global production and distribution systems are integrated, and the possibilities for firms in developing countries to enhance their position in global markets. One of our
11、hopes is that the theory of global val</p><p> Types of Governance in Global Value Chains</p><p> If a theory of global value chain governance is to be useful to policymakers, it should be par
12、simonious. It has to simplify and abstract from an extremely heterogeneous body of evidence, identifying the variables that play a large role in determining patterns of value chain governance while holding others at bay,
13、 at least initially. Clearly, history, institutions, geographic and social contexts, the evolving rules of the game, and path dependence matter; and many factors will influence how firms</p><p> In the 1990
14、s Gereffi and others developed a framework, called “global commodity chains”, that tied the concept of the value-added chain directly to the global organization of industries (see Gereffi and Korzeniewicz 1994). This wor
15、k not only highlighted the importance of coordination across firm boundaries, but also the growing importance of new global buyers (mainly retailers and brand marketers) as key drivers in the formation of globally disper
16、sed and organizationally fragmented production an</p><p> highly competent supply-base upon which global-scale production and distribution systems could be built without direct ownership.</p><p&g
17、t; By highlighting explicit coordination in dis-integrated chains and contrasting them to the relationships contained within vertically integrated, or “producer driven” chains, the global commodity chains framework drew
18、 attention to the role of networks in driving the co-evolution of cross-border industrial organization. However, the global commodity chains framework did not adequately specify the variety of network forms that more rec
19、ent field research has uncovered.</p><p> While, research on the horticulture industry (Dolan and Humphrey 2000) and the footwear industry (Schmitz and Knorringa 2000) reinforced Gereffi's notion that g
20、lobal buyers (retailers, marketers, and traders) can and do exert a high degree of control over spatially dispersed value chains even when they did not own production, transport or processing facilities, recent research
21、on global production has highlighted other important forms of coordination.</p><p> Work on the electronics industry and contract manufacturing by Sturgeon (2002) and by Sturgeon and Lee (2001) contrasted t
22、hree types of supply relationships, based on the degree of standardization of product and process: (1) the "commodity supplier" that provides standard products through arm's length market relationships, (2)
23、 the "captive supplier" that makes non- standard products using machinery dedicated to the buyer's needs, and (3) the "turn-key supplier" that produces customized products </p><p> U
24、sing the approaches outlined above and empirical reference points taken from many studies of global value chains,7 we propose a more complete typology of value-chain governance. We acknowledge, as do most other framework
25、s that seek to explain industry organization — from transactions costs to global commodity chains to organizational theory — that market-based relationships among firms and vertically integrated firms (hierarchies) make
26、up opposite ends of a spectrum of explicit coordination, an</p><p> Markets. Market linkages do not have to be completely transitory, as is typical of spot markets; they can persist over time, with repeat t
27、ransactions. The essential point is that the costs of switching to new partners are low for both parties.</p><p> Modular value chains. Typically, suppliers in modular value chains make products to a custom
28、er's specifications, which may be more or less detailed. However, when providing “turn-key services” suppliers take full responsibility for competencies surrounding process technology, use generic machinery that limi
29、ts transaction- specific investments, and make capital outlays for components and materials on behalf of customers.</p><p> Relational value chains. In these networks we see complex interactions between buy
30、ers and sellers, which often creates mutual dependence and high levels of asset specificity. This may be managed through reputation, or family and ethnic ties. Many authors have highlighted the role of spatial proximity
31、in supporting relational value chain linkages, but trust and reputation might well function in spatially dispersed networks where relationships are built-up over time or are based on dispersed famil</p><p>
32、 Captive value chains. In these networks, small suppliers are transactionally dependent on much larger buyers. Suppliers face significant switching costs and are, therefore, "captive". Such networks are frequen
33、tly characterized by a high degree of monitoring and control by lead firms.</p><p> Hierarchy. This governance form is characterized by vertical integration. The dominant form of governance is managerial co
34、ntrol, flowing from managers to subordinates, or from headquarters to subsidiaries and affiliates.</p><p> A Theory of Value Chain Governance</p><p> Having laid out this typology, our next st
35、ep is to develop an operational theory of global value chain governance. Under which conditions would we expect market, modular, relational, captive, or vertically integrated global value chain governance to arise? Build
36、ing on the work cited above, we will identify and discuss three key determinants of value chain governance patterns: complexity of transactions; codifiability of information; and capability of suppliers. In so doing, we
37、 acknowledge the p</p><p> Lead firms increase complexity when they place new demands on the value chain, such as when they seek just-in-time supply and when they increase product differentiation. However,
38、lead firms also adopt strategies to reduce the complexity of these transactions. One important way of doing this is through the development of technical and process standards. The complexity of information transmitted be
39、tween firms can be reduced through the adoption of technical standards that codify information and al</p><p> At the same time, the integration of new suppliers into global value chains also increases coord
40、ination challenges. Keesing and Lall (1992) argue that producers in developing countries are expected to meet requirements that frequently do not (yet) apply to their domestic markets. This creates a gap between the capa
41、bilities required for the domestic market and those required for the export market, which raises the degree of monitoring and control required by buyers.</p><p> These considerations lead us to construct a
42、theory of value chain governance based on three factors:</p><p> The complexity of information and knowledge transfer required to sustain a particular transaction, particularly with respect to product and p
43、rocess specifications;</p><p> the extent to which this information and knowledge can be codified and, therefore, transmitted efficiently and without transaction-specific investment between the parties to t
44、he transaction; and</p><p> the capabilities of actual and potential suppliers in relation to the requirements of the transaction.</p><p><b> 譯 文:</b></p><p><b&g
45、t; 全球價(jià)值鏈治理</b></p><p><b> 摘要</b></p><p> 本文建立了一個(gè)理論框架來幫助說明全球價(jià)值鏈的治理模式。它利用三種理論——交易成本經(jīng)濟(jì)學(xué),生產(chǎn)網(wǎng)絡(luò),技術(shù)能力和企業(yè)層面的學(xué)習(xí)能力,來識(shí)別三個(gè)在全球價(jià)值鏈?zhǔn)侵卫砗妥兓邪缪葜匾巧淖兞?。它們是:?)交易的復(fù)雜程度;(2)識(shí)別交易的能力;(3)供應(yīng)能力。這一理論把全
46、球價(jià)值鏈治理模式分為五種:等級(jí)型,領(lǐng)導(dǎo)型,關(guān)系型,模塊型和市場型——按照合作意愿和權(quán)力的不對(duì)稱性從高向低排列。本文通過四個(gè)簡短的工業(yè)個(gè)案研究強(qiáng)調(diào)了動(dòng)態(tài)和重疊全球價(jià)值鏈治理:自行車、服裝、園藝和電子產(chǎn)業(yè)集中分析了全球價(jià)值鏈治理的動(dòng)力和重疊的本質(zhì)。</p><p> 關(guān)鍵詞 全球價(jià)值鏈 治理 網(wǎng)絡(luò) 交易成本 價(jià)值鏈模塊</p><p><b> 引言</b>&
47、lt;/p><p> 在過去的幾十年里,全球經(jīng)濟(jì)發(fā)生了巨大的變化,尤其在國際貿(mào)易和產(chǎn)業(yè)組織方面。當(dāng)代經(jīng)濟(jì)最重要的兩個(gè)新特征是生產(chǎn)和貿(mào)易的全球化,極大地推動(dòng)了發(fā)展中國家生產(chǎn)能力,跨國公司的垂直解體??鐕局饾u把它們的核心競爭力專注于在營銷和服務(wù)方面的產(chǎn)業(yè)創(chuàng)新、產(chǎn)品戰(zhàn)略、市場服務(wù)的高附加值環(huán)節(jié)集中,同時(shí)大力削減一些非核心的功能如普通服務(wù)和批量生產(chǎn)等。本文的目的是為更好的理解全球價(jià)值鏈治理結(jié)構(gòu)的轉(zhuǎn)變提供理論框架。我們希
48、望能夠?yàn)楝F(xiàn)實(shí)世界存在的價(jià)值鏈治理模式的治理提供一些普遍適用的基本原則。</p><p> 全球范圍內(nèi)生產(chǎn)組織的演變不僅僅影響公司發(fā)展和產(chǎn)業(yè)結(jié)構(gòu),而且對(duì)國家在全球經(jīng)濟(jì)中如何及為何前進(jìn)與后退都有著極大的影響。全球價(jià)值鏈的研究和政策制訂工作對(duì)全球生產(chǎn)和分配體系組織方式及發(fā)展中國家提升其在國際市場競爭地位的可能性進(jìn)行了探討。我們的愿望之一就是為各國制訂產(chǎn)業(yè)升級(jí)、經(jīng)濟(jì)發(fā)展、就業(yè)創(chuàng)造、減輕貧困相關(guān)政策提供一定的借鑒。<
49、;/p><p> 一、全球價(jià)值鏈治理類型</p><p> 如果全球價(jià)值鏈治理理論對(duì)決策者是有用的話,那么它應(yīng)該是節(jié)省的。它應(yīng)該對(duì)極端復(fù)雜的客觀情況進(jìn)行簡化和提煉,辨別在決定價(jià)值鏈治理模式中占重要地位的變量,即使在其它變量不變,起碼最開始應(yīng)該是這樣。很明顯,歷史,社會(huì)體制,地理環(huán)境和社會(huì)背景,游戲規(guī)則的演變,路徑依賴問題和許多別的因素會(huì)影響公司和企業(yè)群體在全球經(jīng)濟(jì)中是如何鏈接起來的。然而,
50、一個(gè)簡單的框架是有用的,因?yàn)樗蛛x了關(guān)鍵變量并為潛藏在具體的經(jīng)驗(yàn)情況下的根本動(dòng)力提供了一個(gè)清晰的觀點(diǎn)。我們的目的是建立一個(gè)最簡單的理論框架,能產(chǎn)生與現(xiàn)實(shí)世界結(jié)果緊密相關(guān)的結(jié)論。</p><p> 上世紀(jì)九十年代Gereffi和其他學(xué)者提出了全球商品鏈的理論框架。這一理論直接將價(jià)值增值鏈的概念與全球產(chǎn)業(yè)組織直接聯(lián)系了起來。這一框架不僅強(qiáng)調(diào)公司間協(xié)作的重要性,而且強(qiáng)調(diào)了全球新買家(主要是零售商和品牌銷售商)作為關(guān)鍵
51、驅(qū)動(dòng)力在分布全球化、組織片段化生模式產(chǎn)和分銷網(wǎng)絡(luò)形成過程中日益增強(qiáng)的地位。Gereffi(1994)使用“購買者驅(qū)動(dòng)的全球商品鏈”來說明全球買家是如何使用明確的合作來幫助建立一個(gè)高度勝任的供應(yīng)基礎(chǔ),使全球化規(guī)模的生產(chǎn)和分銷體系可以在沒有直接所有權(quán)的情況下建立起來。</p><p> 通過強(qiáng)調(diào)非一體化鏈條上的明確合作并比較它和垂直一體的關(guān)系,或者是和生產(chǎn)者驅(qū)動(dòng)鏈條進(jìn)行比較,全球商品鏈框架關(guān)注網(wǎng)絡(luò)在驅(qū)動(dòng)協(xié)同化跨境產(chǎn)
52、業(yè)組織演進(jìn)中扮演的角色。然而,最近的實(shí)地研究表明全球商品鏈框架不能足以說明各種各樣的網(wǎng)絡(luò)模式。同時(shí),在園藝業(yè)(Dolan,Humphrey,2000)和鞋類(Schmitz,Knorringa,2000)的研究鞏固了Gereffi的觀點(diǎn),即全球買家(零售商,營銷商和貿(mào)易商)可以并且能夠?qū)臻g上分散的價(jià)值鏈進(jìn)行了高度控制,即使它們并不擁有產(chǎn)品,運(yùn)輸和加工設(shè)備,最近關(guān)于全球生產(chǎn)的研究強(qiáng)調(diào)了協(xié)作的其它重要模式。</p><
53、p> Sturgeon致力于電子工業(yè)和合同制造業(yè)的研究(2002,Sturgeon),并且和Lee(2001)對(duì)比了三種供應(yīng)關(guān)系類型,基于生產(chǎn)和加工的標(biāo)準(zhǔn)化程度:(1)商品供應(yīng)商,通過公平地市場關(guān)系提供標(biāo)準(zhǔn)的產(chǎn)品;(2)領(lǐng)導(dǎo)型供應(yīng)商,通過體制致力于生產(chǎn)顧客需要的非標(biāo)準(zhǔn)化產(chǎn)品 (3)交鑰匙應(yīng)商, 通過使用靈活的生產(chǎn)設(shè)備,使具有按客戶需求定制產(chǎn)品的能力。這一分析強(qiáng)調(diào)了公司間信息交換和生產(chǎn)設(shè)備中資產(chǎn)特異性程度的復(fù)雜性。Sturgeon
54、(2002)把依靠交鑰匙供應(yīng)商的生產(chǎn)體系定義為“模塊化生產(chǎn)網(wǎng)絡(luò)”,因?yàn)橐粋€(gè)高度勝任的供應(yīng)商可能會(huì)根據(jù)需要在全球化生產(chǎn)安排中增加或者減少份額。與此同時(shí),Humphrey和Schmitz(2000;2002)辨析了供應(yīng)商和購買這間有如等級(jí)體系的關(guān)系,這種情況與“領(lǐng)導(dǎo)型體系下的供應(yīng)商”相對(duì)應(yīng),</p><p> Humphrey和Schmitz強(qiáng)調(diào)了供應(yīng)商權(quán)限在供應(yīng)商決定對(duì)購買者附屬程度中所扮演的角色。如果全球買家需
55、要對(duì)供應(yīng)商權(quán)限投資,他們不僅需要詳細(xì)說明供應(yīng)商需要遵循的生產(chǎn)和加工的參數(shù),還要保證其投資額在這一供應(yīng)商上的優(yōu)勢地位,如果不是作為唯一的顧客。</p><p> 使用上述概念以及從許多全球價(jià)值鏈研究中取得的經(jīng)驗(yàn)參考點(diǎn),我們提出了一個(gè)更完整的價(jià)值鏈治理模式分類的辦法。我們承認(rèn),和許多其他試圖說明產(chǎn)業(yè)組織的理論框架一樣——從交易成本到全球商品鏈再到組織理論——以市場為基礎(chǔ)的公司間關(guān)系和垂直一體化的公司等級(jí)制產(chǎn)生了與明
56、確合作程度截然相反的兩個(gè)結(jié)果,而網(wǎng)絡(luò)關(guān)系模式則構(gòu)成了全球價(jià)值鏈治理的中間部分。我們加強(qiáng)的這個(gè)概念是基于三種有區(qū)別的網(wǎng)絡(luò)模式分類的延伸,即:模塊型,關(guān)系型和領(lǐng)導(dǎo)型。這樣我們的分類方法區(qū)分出五種基本的價(jià)值鏈治理模式。它們是分析型的,而不是經(jīng)驗(yàn)總結(jié)型的,盡管它們中都有一部分是來自于實(shí)際觀察。它們包括:</p><p> 1、市場型。市場聯(lián)系并不一定都是完全短暫的,和典型的現(xiàn)貨交易市場一樣,公司間的合作也可能會(huì)持續(xù)很久
57、,并且重復(fù)交易。重點(diǎn)是轉(zhuǎn)換新的合作伙伴的成本對(duì)雙方來說都很低。</p><p> 2、模塊型價(jià)值鏈。典型的模塊型價(jià)值鏈中的供應(yīng)商按照顧客要求生產(chǎn)產(chǎn)品,這只是細(xì)節(jié)上的或多或少的差別。然而,當(dāng)提供交鑰匙服務(wù)的供應(yīng)商對(duì)加工技術(shù)能力承擔(dān)全部責(zé)任,使用普通設(shè)備對(duì)交易型投資有限制性,以及代表顧客對(duì)零部件和原材料進(jìn)行資本支出。</p><p> 3、關(guān)系型價(jià)值鏈。在這種網(wǎng)絡(luò)中我們可以了解到買賣雙方中
58、復(fù)雜的相互影響,基于此常常會(huì)產(chǎn)生相互依賴和高度的資產(chǎn)特異性。這種模式可能通過個(gè)人聲望、家族和種族之間的連結(jié)來完成。許多學(xué)者則強(qiáng)調(diào)空間上的接近在輔助聯(lián)接關(guān)系型價(jià)值鏈上的地位,但是信任和聲譽(yù)在空間分散網(wǎng)絡(luò)中起到了良好的功效,而這種關(guān)系往往是建立在長期合作中,分散的家族和社會(huì)群體上的。</p><p> 4、領(lǐng)導(dǎo)型價(jià)值鏈。在這些網(wǎng)絡(luò)中,小型供應(yīng)商對(duì)大的購買商有著高度的依賴性。供應(yīng)商面臨著重大的轉(zhuǎn)換成本,因此,對(duì)于“領(lǐng)
59、導(dǎo)級(jí)”也是如此。這種網(wǎng)絡(luò)的通常特征是供應(yīng)商被領(lǐng)導(dǎo)企業(yè)高度監(jiān)視和控制。</p><p> 5、等級(jí)制。這一治理模式的特點(diǎn)是通過垂直一體化治理。而治理的主要形式是管理控制,沿著從管理者到下級(jí),或者從總公司到分子公司或分支機(jī)構(gòu)的方向。</p><p><b> 2、價(jià)格鏈治理理論</b></p><p> 基于這種分類方法的提出,我們下一步就是
60、研究全球價(jià)值鏈治理的操作理論。在哪種情況下我們會(huì)期望出現(xiàn)市場型、模塊型、關(guān)系型、領(lǐng)導(dǎo)型或垂直一體化的全球價(jià)值鏈治理模式?;趯?duì)上文的引用,我們識(shí)別和討論價(jià)值鏈治理模式中的三個(gè)關(guān)鍵因素:交易的復(fù)雜性,識(shí)別供應(yīng)商的交易的能力和供應(yīng)能力。通過這樣做,我們了解到,資產(chǎn)特異性問題可以通過交易成本經(jīng)濟(jì)學(xué)被識(shí)別,同時(shí)強(qiáng)調(diào)放在所謂的“領(lǐng)導(dǎo)型”交易成本中,這種成本包括在價(jià)值鏈中協(xié)調(diào)活動(dòng)的成本。通常認(rèn)為這種協(xié)調(diào)的,或全球化的交易成本會(huì)上升,當(dāng)價(jià)值鏈生產(chǎn)非標(biāo)
61、準(zhǔn)化產(chǎn)品時(shí),一體化結(jié)構(gòu)產(chǎn)品或?qū)r(shí)間敏感的產(chǎn)品時(shí)。</p><p> 當(dāng)他們在價(jià)值鏈中被寄予新的要求,例如尋找當(dāng)下需要的供應(yīng)品和增加產(chǎn)品差異性時(shí)機(jī),領(lǐng)導(dǎo)企業(yè)的復(fù)雜性就增加了。然而,領(lǐng)導(dǎo)企業(yè)同時(shí)也會(huì)采用降低交易復(fù)雜性的措施。一種重要的方法就是通過技術(shù)和加工標(biāo)準(zhǔn)的研發(fā)。公司之間信息傳遞的復(fù)雜性可以通過采用技術(shù)標(biāo)準(zhǔn)將信息編成法典和允許貿(mào)易伙伴之間傳遞原始數(shù)據(jù)來降低。這些標(biāo)準(zhǔn)在價(jià)值鏈各環(huán)節(jié)的應(yīng)用距離整個(gè)鏈條的提升還有很長
62、的距離。當(dāng)這些約定的規(guī)范化傳遞標(biāo)準(zhǔn)被所有企業(yè)所熟知并遵循時(shí),這個(gè)鏈條將獲得許多好處,例如那些被認(rèn)同的模塊化產(chǎn)品設(shè)計(jì),尤其是保留人們的努力成果,通過重復(fù)利用基礎(chǔ)系統(tǒng),或者是模塊化,就好像新產(chǎn)品被引進(jìn)。在模塊化價(jià)值鏈范圍內(nèi),供應(yīng)商和客戶之間容易可以建立和中斷聯(lián)系,這導(dǎo)致了不固定的和靈活的網(wǎng)絡(luò)結(jié)構(gòu)。同時(shí)其動(dòng)力來源與市場型很類似,兩種模式保留著本質(zhì)上的差異,因?yàn)榉莾r(jià)格信息在公司間流動(dòng)的大量變量,即使以一種規(guī)范的形式。此外,產(chǎn)品的高度差異性可以通
63、過有限的信息來提供,就好像通過一系列不含糊的,被廣泛接受的參數(shù)來定義差異性。在傳統(tǒng)上,公共和私有機(jī)構(gòu)都可以定義產(chǎn)品的規(guī)格和標(biāo)準(zhǔn),并且在某些情況下有權(quán)驗(yàn)證產(chǎn)品是不是符合這些標(biāo)準(zhǔn)。在與質(zhì)量相關(guān)的標(biāo)準(zhǔn)和認(rèn)證發(fā)展過程中,勞</p><p> 同時(shí),新的供應(yīng)商融入全球價(jià)值鏈也向協(xié)調(diào)提出了挑戰(zhàn)。Keesing和Lall(1992)認(rèn)為發(fā)展中國家的制造商被期望能滿足在其國內(nèi)市場并不適用的各項(xiàng)要求。這使得在國內(nèi)能力要求和國外的
64、能力要求上出現(xiàn)了差距,也提高了購買者監(jiān)視和控制能力。</p><p> 這些事項(xiàng)引導(dǎo)我們構(gòu)建一個(gè)基于以下三要素的價(jià)值鏈治理理論:</p><p> A 維持一樁特殊的交易,尤其考慮到產(chǎn)品和加工規(guī)模所需要的信息和知識(shí)傳遞的復(fù)雜性。</p><p> B 信息和知識(shí)規(guī)范化程度,其結(jié)果是可以有效傳輸而且不需要在交易的各個(gè)環(huán)節(jié)額外專業(yè)化投資。</p>&
溫馨提示
- 1. 本站所有資源如無特殊說明,都需要本地電腦安裝OFFICE2007和PDF閱讀器。圖紙軟件為CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.壓縮文件請(qǐng)下載最新的WinRAR軟件解壓。
- 2. 本站的文檔不包含任何第三方提供的附件圖紙等,如果需要附件,請(qǐng)聯(lián)系上傳者。文件的所有權(quán)益歸上傳用戶所有。
- 3. 本站RAR壓縮包中若帶圖紙,網(wǎng)頁內(nèi)容里面會(huì)有圖紙預(yù)覽,若沒有圖紙預(yù)覽就沒有圖紙。
- 4. 未經(jīng)權(quán)益所有人同意不得將文件中的內(nèi)容挪作商業(yè)或盈利用途。
- 5. 眾賞文庫僅提供信息存儲(chǔ)空間,僅對(duì)用戶上傳內(nèi)容的表現(xiàn)方式做保護(hù)處理,對(duì)用戶上傳分享的文檔內(nèi)容本身不做任何修改或編輯,并不能對(duì)任何下載內(nèi)容負(fù)責(zé)。
- 6. 下載文件中如有侵權(quán)或不適當(dāng)內(nèi)容,請(qǐng)與我們聯(lián)系,我們立即糾正。
- 7. 本站不保證下載資源的準(zhǔn)確性、安全性和完整性, 同時(shí)也不承擔(dān)用戶因使用這些下載資源對(duì)自己和他人造成任何形式的傷害或損失。
最新文檔
- 全球價(jià)值鏈治理【外文翻譯】
- 全球價(jià)值鏈的治理【外文翻譯】
- 全球價(jià)值鏈的治理【外文翻譯】
- 全球價(jià)值鏈下產(chǎn)業(yè)升級(jí)【外文翻譯】
- 外文翻譯--對(duì)全球價(jià)值鏈的投入如何影響產(chǎn)業(yè)集群的升級(jí)(節(jié)選)
- 如何嵌入全球價(jià)值鏈影響產(chǎn)業(yè)集群升級(jí)【外文翻譯】
- 嵌入全球價(jià)值鏈如何影響產(chǎn)業(yè)集群升級(jí)?【外文翻譯】
- 全球航空價(jià)值鏈爭論
- 25400.高速鐵路全球價(jià)值鏈治理研究
- 物流集群——如何運(yùn)用區(qū)域價(jià)值鏈來加快全球供應(yīng)鏈【外文翻譯】
- 產(chǎn)權(quán)強(qiáng)度、市場勢力和全球價(jià)值鏈治理研究.pdf
- 外文翻譯--全球價(jià)值鏈下的本地升級(jí)近期的研究成果
- 外文翻譯--全球價(jià)值鏈下的本地升級(jí):近期的研究成果
- 外文翻譯--全球價(jià)值鏈下的本地升級(jí)近期的研究成果
- 外文翻譯--全球價(jià)值鏈下的本地升級(jí)近期的研究成果
- 如何在全球價(jià)值鏈中引入影響產(chǎn)業(yè)集群的升級(jí)?【外文翻譯】
- 對(duì)全球價(jià)值鏈的投入如何影響產(chǎn)業(yè)集群的升級(jí)【外文翻譯】
- 研發(fā),價(jià)值鏈定位與全球電子產(chǎn)業(yè)的企業(yè)績效[外文翻譯]
- 外文翻譯--全球價(jià)值鏈下的本地升級(jí):近期的研究成果.docx
- 外文翻譯--全球價(jià)值鏈下的本地升級(jí)近期的研究成果(英文)
評(píng)論
0/150
提交評(píng)論