版權(quán)說(shuō)明:本文檔由用戶(hù)提供并上傳,收益歸屬內(nèi)容提供方,若內(nèi)容存在侵權(quán),請(qǐng)進(jìn)行舉報(bào)或認(rèn)領(lǐng)
文檔簡(jiǎn)介
1、<p><b> 中文3950字</b></p><p><b> 外文原文</b></p><p> International Monetary and Financial Arrangements: Present and Future</p><p> 3. National economic p
2、olicies under the present international monetary system</p><p> In this part, we examine central bank independence and monetary and fiscal policies under the present international monetary system. We also e
3、xamine global financial integration and the effectiveness of monetary policy.</p><p> 3.1. Central bank independence</p><p> In recent years, many nations have passed laws removing government
4、control on their central bank (i.e., making their central bank more independent) in order to overcome the inflationary bias that was otherwise believed to exist in the conduct of monetary policy. The central banks of som
5、e nations, such as Switzerland and Germany, have enjoyed a high degree of independence during most of the postwar period. Recently, Canada, Chile, and New Zealand enacted legislation to make their central banks mo</p&
6、gt;<p> But what is meant by central bank independence? Fisher (1995) introduced the distinction between goal independence and instrument independence. A central bank has goal independence if it can set its own
7、goals, such as the rate of inflation that the nation should aim for. Instrument independence means that the central bank has control over the levers of monetary policy. That is, it has no obligation to finance government
8、 deficits, directly or indirectly, and that it has the power to set interest</p><p> Theoretically, there are two different approaches to central bank independence. One is the conservative-banker approach o
9、f Rogoff (1985) and the other is the principal-agent approach of Walsh (1995). In the conservative-banker approach, the central bank has both goal and instrument independence. Presumably, the conservative banker will wei
10、gh deviations of both inflation and output from target levels in setting monetary policy, but with a bias in favor of lower inflation, even if this comes at th</p><p> Today, there is general agreement that
11、 a central bank should have instrument, but not goal independence. There are two reasons for this. The first is that the monetary goal of the nation should reflect the social welfare function of the nation and not just t
12、he preferences of the central bank governor. The second is that there is the need to coordinate monetary and fiscal policies to avoid their operating at cross purposes of each other. Central bank accountability, however,
13、 is needed to ensure t</p><p> 3.2. Central bank independence and inflation</p><p> As expected, a number of empirical studies have shown an inverse relationship between central bank independe
14、nce and the rate of inflation in industrial countries. That is, the more independent the central bank of an industrial country is, the lower the rate of inflation in the nation. One of the most comprehensive of these stu
15、dies is the one by Alesina and Summers (1993). The authors included the following 16 industrial countries in the study: Australia, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, France, Germany</p><p> The sample period was fro
16、m 1955 to 1988. As in previous studies, the authors found a negative correlation between the level of central bank independence and the rate of inflation. They also found that the more independent a central bank was, the
17、 smaller was the variability of the inflation rate (because of the positive correlation between the level and variability of inflation).</p><p> As it is well known, however, correlation does not establish
18、causality. That is, the negative correlation between central bank independence and inflation found in empirical studies does not imply that the former causes the latter. It may very well be that countries with a stronger
19、 aversion to inflation are more likely to give more independence to their central banks. Thus, it is the inflation aversion in the nation that gives rise both to lower inflation and to a more independent central bank in&
20、lt;/p><p> As support for central bank independence has increased around the world, so has the tendency to entrust to central banks the sole function of achieving a given inflation target or range. This, howev
21、er, raises the question of whether it would be more appropriate to entrust the central bank with a target that is more directly controllable by the central bank, such as the growth of a narrow money aggregate, rather tha
22、n a specific inflation target. Setting an inflation target, however, seems more ap</p><p> As a result, it is better to assign an explicit inflation target to the central bank and provide it with instrument
23、 independence to pursue the inflation target. As to why the central bank should be given a specific inflation target rather than a growth-of-real-GDP or rate-of-unemployment target, the answer is that inflation is a mone
24、tary phenomenon while the rate of growth of real GDP and the rate of unemployment are real phenomena. Real phenomena are, of course, affected by monetary phenomena, </p><p> Thus, a country that is trying t
25、o move from a high to a low inflation environment would do well to adopt a fixed rather than a variable exchange rate system as a means of anchoring monetary policy and market expectations. Many developing countries, how
26、ever, have been moving toward greater exchange-rate flexibility in order to cope better with big swings in foreign capital flows.</p><p> Although many empirical studies have found a negative correlation be
27、tween central bank independence and inflation in industrial countries, this is not the case for developing countries. Cukierman (1992) found a positive, not a negative, relationship between central bank independence and
28、inflation for a group of 70 developing countries that he studied over the 1950–1989 period. This, however, may be due to the fact that the central banks of many developing countries are independent legally but no</p&g
29、t;<p> 3.3. Central bank independence, the real economy, and fiscal deficits</p><p> Does the lower inflation rate with an independent central bank come at the expense of growth of output for the na
30、tion? Alesina and Summers (1993) found no negative correlation between central bank independence and average growth of real GDP or the variability of growth of real GDP for the same 16 industrial countries that they used
31、 to examine the relationship between central bank independence and inflation over the 1955–1988 period. Barro (1995) and Sarel (1996) confirm this for inflation rates </p><p> The same conclusion was reache
32、d for industrial nations in another study by Cukierman, Kalaitzidakis, Summers, and Webb (1992) by regressing the nation’s growth rate of real GDP on the degree of central bank independence, the initial level of real GDP
33、 in the nation, the initial level of primary and secondary education in the nation, and the nation’s terms of trade. For developing nations, however, Cukierman, Kalaitzidakis, Summers, and Webb found that central bank in
34、dependence did have a signific</p><p> Empirical studies were also conducted to examine the relationship between central bank independence and fiscal deficits as a percentage of GDP in the nation. The expec
35、tation was that a more independent central bank would be able to resist better government efforts to monetize fiscal deficits and thus lead to lower long-run average fiscal deficits as a percentage of GDP in the nation.
36、Such a negative relationship was in fact found by Parkin (1987) and Grilli et al. (1991) for industrial countries</p><p> Although empirical studies have found no relationship between central bank independe
37、nce and the rate of economic growth in industrial nations, there is a theoretical reason for expecting that a central bank that can set its own inflation target and operate independently of the fiscal authority of the na
38、tion can lead to a lower rate of growth in the nation. This can result when there is a conflict between the goals of the monetary and the fiscal authority of the nation.Then monetary and fiscal po</p><p> T
39、hus, the general tendency for economists today of endorsing the separation of power in the conduct of monetary and fiscal policies may not be the best policy to maximize non-inflationary growth in the nation (see Nordhau
40、s, 1994). Better results can be obtained by the coordination of monetary and fiscal policies. It is not just that in the absence of such a coordination, fiscal and monetary authorities might pursue contradictory goals. S
41、uboptimal results may arise simply because of the different</p><p> 國(guó)際貨幣和金融安排:現(xiàn)狀與未來(lái)</p><p> 3.在目前的國(guó)際貨幣體系下的國(guó)家經(jīng)濟(jì)政策</p><p> 在這一部分,我們研究在現(xiàn)行國(guó)際貨幣體系下的中央銀行的獨(dú)立性、貨幣和財(cái)政政策。我們還研究全球金融一體化和貨幣政策的有
42、效性。</p><p> 3.1 中央銀行的獨(dú)立性</p><p> 近年來(lái),許多國(guó)家都通過(guò)法律取消政府對(duì)中央銀行的控制力(即,使他們的中央銀行更加獨(dú)立)以克服存在于貨幣政策中對(duì)通貨膨脹的成見(jiàn)。一些國(guó)家的中央銀行,如瑞士和德國(guó)的中央銀行,在戰(zhàn)后時(shí)期都享有高度的獨(dú)立性。最近,加拿大、智利和新西蘭通過(guò)立法使他們的中央銀行更加獨(dú)立。1997年五月,英國(guó)也實(shí)行了相同的政策。共同的經(jīng)濟(jì)改革在拉丁
43、美洲和中歐、東歐的一些前共產(chǎn)主義國(guó)家都已建立獨(dú)立的中央銀行,至少在法律上,已實(shí)行日常運(yùn)作。馬斯特里赫特條約禁止中央銀行市服從政府的指示,作為條件之一,為歐洲貨幣聯(lián)盟。為確保央行的獨(dú)立性,該條約還要求央行行長(zhǎng)任期至少為五年。更重要的是,該條約禁止央行從政府直接購(gòu)買(mǎi)債務(wù)工具及提供設(shè)施信貸給政府。即中央銀行獨(dú)立于政治壓力會(huì)達(dá)到一個(gè)較低的通脹率。</p><p> 但何謂中央銀行的獨(dú)立性?費(fèi)舍爾(1995)介紹了目標(biāo)獨(dú)
44、立性和相對(duì)獨(dú)立的區(qū)別。中央銀行具有目標(biāo)獨(dú)立性,如果它可以設(shè)置自己的目標(biāo),諸如國(guó)家應(yīng)該瞄準(zhǔn)的通貨膨脹率。相對(duì)獨(dú)立性意味著央行有貨幣政策上的杠桿控制力。也就是說(shuō),,它對(duì)政府赤字融資沒(méi)有直接或間接的責(zé)任,但它有權(quán)力來(lái)設(shè)定利率。當(dāng)然,央行有目標(biāo)獨(dú)立性和相對(duì)獨(dú)立性,可以設(shè)定自己的貨幣目標(biāo),是貨幣自由利用其掌握的工具以實(shí)現(xiàn)目標(biāo)。即使有最獨(dú)立中央銀行的國(guó)家,但政府仍超越中央銀行,它通常在國(guó)家擁有的匯率安排類(lèi)型上有最后決定權(quán),并改變固定匯率系統(tǒng)中的匯率
45、,或通過(guò)對(duì)外匯市場(chǎng)的干預(yù)制度,影響水平,如果國(guó)家的匯率制度有一個(gè)靈活的選擇(Capie,1998)。</p><p> 從理論上講,在中央銀行的獨(dú)立性上有兩個(gè)不同的方法。其一是羅格夫(1985年)的保守的銀行家的方法,其他的是沃爾什(1995年)的委托代理的方式。保守的銀行家認(rèn)為,央行同時(shí)具有絕對(duì)和相對(duì)的獨(dú)立性。據(jù)推測(cè),保守的銀行家將從目標(biāo)制定貨幣政策的水平上權(quán)衡通貨膨脹和產(chǎn)出的偏差,但在通貨膨脹率較低偏向時(shí),
46、可能要以低增長(zhǎng)為代價(jià)。在委托代理的做法上,另一方面,中央銀行家相對(duì)獨(dú)立性,但不是絕對(duì)獨(dú)立性。也就是說(shuō),政府制定貨幣目標(biāo),如為國(guó)家的通貨膨脹率,然后央行自由掌握任何一種貨幣工具來(lái)實(shí)現(xiàn)貨幣目標(biāo)。委托代理的目標(biāo)是新西蘭最明確的例子,那里的央行行長(zhǎng)正式同意遵守由政府制定的通脹目標(biāo)。在加拿大和英國(guó),如果超過(guò)了通貨膨脹的限定范圍,中央銀行的聲譽(yù)可能會(huì)受其影響。</p><p> 今天,人們普遍認(rèn)為,央行應(yīng)該有相對(duì)政策,而不
47、是完全獨(dú)立的貨幣政策。有兩個(gè)原因來(lái)說(shuō)明這個(gè)。首先,一個(gè)國(guó)家的貨幣政策應(yīng)該反映國(guó)家的社會(huì)財(cái)富,而不是僅僅是中央銀行行長(zhǎng)的偏好。第二,需要協(xié)調(diào)貨幣和財(cái)政政策,以避免他們工作中的相互作用。然而,中央銀行問(wèn)責(zé)制需要確保國(guó)家的貨幣目標(biāo),在事實(shí)上,這是國(guó)家的中央銀行的追求。在新西蘭,央行行長(zhǎng)要對(duì)財(cái)政部長(zhǎng)負(fù)責(zé)。在美國(guó),聯(lián)邦儲(chǔ)備銀行或美聯(lián)儲(chǔ)(美國(guó)中央銀行)一般向國(guó)會(huì)負(fù)責(zé),它必須經(jīng)美聯(lián)儲(chǔ)選擇的主席批準(zhǔn)并且可以解釋其政策。在德國(guó),聯(lián)邦銀行對(duì)辯護(hù)貨幣政策的廣
48、大市民負(fù)責(zé)。近幾年,越來(lái)越多的國(guó)家跟隨新西蘭的做法,為央行設(shè)定明確的通貨膨脹率。政府貨幣政策要建立信譽(yù),提供透明度和問(wèn)責(zé)制是非常重要的。中央銀行越可信,越能夠在經(jīng)濟(jì)放緩情況下不削減利率,也不引發(fā)較高的通貨膨脹預(yù)期和較高的長(zhǎng)期利率,或提高利率以遏制通脹壓力,恐懼可能會(huì)引發(fā)經(jīng)濟(jì)衰退。包括美國(guó)在內(nèi)的幾個(gè)國(guó)家的中央銀行繼續(xù)增加透明度和問(wèn)責(zé)制,重視可信度和有效性,最近也已經(jīng)開(kāi)始解釋自己的決策程序(包括美聯(lián)儲(chǔ)會(huì)議紀(jì)要滯后出版)和操作貨幣政策的程序。
49、然而,事實(shí)上美聯(lián)儲(chǔ)相對(duì)于其他大多數(shù)中央銀行,是憲法規(guī)定追求價(jià)格穩(wěn)定和充分就業(yè)</p><p> 3.2 中央銀行的獨(dú)立性與通貨膨脹</p><p> 正如預(yù)期的那樣,一些有經(jīng)驗(yàn)的研究已經(jīng)證實(shí)中央銀行之間的獨(dú)立和工業(yè)國(guó)家的通脹率有反比關(guān)系。也就是說(shuō),工業(yè)國(guó)的央行越獨(dú)立,在全國(guó)范圍內(nèi)的通脹率越低。這些研究中最全面的一個(gè)是由Alesina和薩默斯(1993)提出的。研究中,作者提到了以下16
50、個(gè)工業(yè)國(guó)家:澳大利亞、比利時(shí)、加拿大、丹麥、法國(guó)、德國(guó)、意大利、日本、荷蘭、新西蘭、挪威、西班牙、瑞典、瑞士、英國(guó)和美國(guó)。樣本期間為1955年至1988年。正如在以前的研究中,作者發(fā)現(xiàn)在中央銀行的獨(dú)立程度和通貨膨脹率呈負(fù)相關(guān)。他們還發(fā)現(xiàn)中央銀行越獨(dú)立,通貨膨脹率的變化越?。ㄒ?yàn)橥浰胶屯涀兓收嚓P(guān)關(guān)系)。</p><p> 眾所周知,相關(guān)性并不意味著有因果關(guān)系。也就是說(shuō),實(shí)證研究中中央銀行的獨(dú)立性與通貨膨
51、脹負(fù)相關(guān),并不意味著前者導(dǎo)致了后者。有較強(qiáng)的規(guī)避通脹的國(guó)家更可能給他們的中央銀行更多的獨(dú)立性。因此,通脹厭惡的國(guó)家,會(huì)使通貨膨脹降低和一個(gè)更獨(dú)立的中央銀行,而不是一個(gè)獨(dú)立的中央銀行責(zé)任(即造成)較低的通脹。除非,我們相信法律和機(jī)構(gòu)是完全不相干的,而且對(duì)經(jīng)濟(jì)沒(méi)有任何影響性能(這里的通貨膨脹率)。我們必須了解,其他條件相同的情況下,更獨(dú)立央行比不獨(dú)立的中央銀行更可能形成較低的通貨膨脹率。</p><p> 對(duì)獨(dú)立性
52、中央銀行的支持已經(jīng)在世界各地增加,所以有傾向委托中央銀行來(lái)實(shí)現(xiàn)一個(gè)給定的通貨膨脹目標(biāo)或范圍。然而,委托一個(gè)目標(biāo)越合適,直接由中央銀行控制就越多,如狹窄的增長(zhǎng)貨幣總量而不是具體的通貨膨脹目標(biāo)。然而,在國(guó)家之間設(shè)定通脹目標(biāo),似乎今天貨幣增長(zhǎng)和通貨膨脹之間暴跌關(guān)系更恰當(dāng)。因此,最好是分配一個(gè)明確的通脹目標(biāo)給中央銀行,并提供相對(duì)獨(dú)立性以追求通脹目標(biāo)。至于為何央行應(yīng)給予具體的通貨膨脹目標(biāo),而不是一個(gè)增長(zhǎng)的國(guó)民生產(chǎn)總值或失業(yè)率目標(biāo),是因?yàn)橥ㄘ浥蛎浭?/p>
53、一種貨幣現(xiàn)象,而國(guó)內(nèi)生產(chǎn)總值及失業(yè)率是真實(shí)的現(xiàn)象。當(dāng)然,真實(shí)的現(xiàn)象受貨幣現(xiàn)象,但這里的因果關(guān)系取決于政策和體制,而不是在中央銀行的直接控制之下。在給予中央銀行具體的通貨膨脹目標(biāo)的過(guò)程中,很重要的一點(diǎn)指出,固定匯率比浮動(dòng)匯率的通脹低。因此,一個(gè)國(guó)家如果試圖從高轉(zhuǎn)移到低通貨膨脹的環(huán)境最好還是通過(guò)一個(gè)固定的,而不是浮動(dòng)匯率制度作為錨定貨幣政策手段和市場(chǎng)預(yù)期。許多發(fā)展中國(guó)家,已朝向更大的匯率靈活性改變,以便應(yīng)對(duì)外國(guó)資本流動(dòng)大幅波動(dòng)更好。雖然許多
54、實(shí)證研究已經(jīng)發(fā)現(xiàn)了一種中央銀行的獨(dú)立性和工業(yè)化國(guó)家的通貨膨脹的負(fù)相關(guān)系,這不是發(fā)展中國(guó)家的案例。 Cukierm</p><p> 3.3 央行的獨(dú)立性,實(shí)體經(jīng)濟(jì)和財(cái)政的赤字 </p><p> 是否獨(dú)立中央銀行以較低的通脹率為代價(jià)來(lái)使國(guó)家產(chǎn)出增長(zhǎng)? Alesina和薩默斯(1993)發(fā)現(xiàn)中央銀行的獨(dú)立性,國(guó)內(nèi)生產(chǎn)總值實(shí)際平均增長(zhǎng)率或16個(gè)工業(yè)變異相同國(guó)家中實(shí)際國(guó)民生產(chǎn)總值的增長(zhǎng)率沒(méi)有
55、直接負(fù)相關(guān)關(guān)系,他們用來(lái)研究在1955至88年通貨膨脹時(shí)期中央銀行的獨(dú)立性之間的關(guān)系。巴羅(1995)和薩雷爾西利(1996年)確保低于8%的通貨膨脹率。因此,它似乎并不認(rèn)為中央銀行在從事工業(yè)國(guó)家貿(mào)易時(shí)以較低的增長(zhǎng)速度來(lái)使通貨膨脹率較低。</p><p> 同樣的結(jié)論在工業(yè)國(guó)家由Cukierman,Kalaitzidakis,薩默斯和Webb(1992)寫(xiě)作的另一項(xiàng)研究中也有提到,在中央銀行的獨(dú)立性程度通過(guò)歸納
56、實(shí)際國(guó)民生產(chǎn)總值的國(guó)內(nèi)增長(zhǎng)率,在全國(guó)的實(shí)際GDP初始水平、國(guó)家的小學(xué)和中學(xué)的初始教育水平、民族貿(mào)易的條款。對(duì)于發(fā)展中國(guó)家國(guó)家,但是,Cukierman,Kalaitzidakis,薩默斯和韋伯發(fā)現(xiàn)中央銀行的獨(dú)立性確實(shí)對(duì)經(jīng)濟(jì)增長(zhǎng)顯著正向影響。在大多數(shù)發(fā)展中國(guó)家中,當(dāng)通貨膨脹率高時(shí),以至于更獨(dú)立的中央銀行伴隨的通貨膨脹率越高(鼓勵(lì)增長(zhǎng)),中央銀行的獨(dú)立性越強(qiáng),并且增長(zhǎng)速度更快。由于工業(yè)國(guó)家普遍沒(méi)有面臨著高通貨膨脹,較高的增長(zhǎng)率就不是用于他們
57、。</p><p> 也進(jìn)行了實(shí)證研究,研究中央銀行的獨(dú)立性和財(cái)政赤字占國(guó)內(nèi)生產(chǎn)總值的百分比之間的關(guān)系。人們期望的是一個(gè)更加獨(dú)立的中央銀行能夠更好地促進(jìn)政府對(duì)財(cái)政赤字的努力,從而形成長(zhǎng)期的較低的占國(guó)內(nèi)生產(chǎn)總值的平均比例。這種消極的關(guān)系是由帕金(1987年)和Grilli(1991)等人在工業(yè)國(guó)家發(fā)現(xiàn)的事實(shí)。因此,總體結(jié)論是從實(shí)證研究中可以得到,日期是一個(gè)獨(dú)立的中央銀行關(guān)聯(lián)低通貨膨脹率和國(guó)內(nèi)生產(chǎn)總值的比例降低財(cái)政
58、赤字,但是無(wú)關(guān)工業(yè)國(guó)家的增長(zhǎng)。</p><p> 雖然實(shí)證研究發(fā)現(xiàn)中央銀行的獨(dú)立性和在工業(yè)國(guó)家中的經(jīng)濟(jì)增長(zhǎng)率之間沒(méi)有關(guān)系,有預(yù)期的理論性原因,即央行可以設(shè)定自己的通貨膨脹目標(biāo),獨(dú)立經(jīng)營(yíng)民族,這樣可能導(dǎo)致財(cái)政部門(mén)在一個(gè)國(guó)家的較低成長(zhǎng)率。這可能會(huì)導(dǎo)致貨幣目標(biāo)和民族財(cái)政之間的沖突。當(dāng)時(shí)的金融和財(cái)政政策可以在相互的目的中移動(dòng),并導(dǎo)致國(guó)家的經(jīng)濟(jì)表現(xiàn)為次優(yōu)。因此,中央銀行不可以過(guò)于獨(dú)立。例如,中央銀行過(guò)分通貨膨脹厭惡,如央
59、行,可能過(guò)度抑制全國(guó)經(jīng)濟(jì)增長(zhǎng)。更好地為國(guó)家的經(jīng)濟(jì)表現(xiàn),會(huì)使財(cái)政和貨幣政策的協(xié)調(diào)。這可以通過(guò)賦予中央銀行獨(dú)立文書(shū),但不是獨(dú)立的最終目的。</p><p> 因此,經(jīng)濟(jì)學(xué)家們普遍贊同分離傾向,今日在貨幣和財(cái)政政策的行為中可能不是權(quán)力最好的政策,以最大限度地發(fā)揮非通貨膨脹在全國(guó)的增長(zhǎng)(見(jiàn)諾德豪斯,1994年)。更好的結(jié)果可以通過(guò)協(xié)調(diào)貨幣政策和財(cái)政政策。這不僅是在這樣一個(gè)缺乏協(xié)調(diào),財(cái)政和貨幣當(dāng)局可能相互矛盾的目標(biāo)追求的
溫馨提示
- 1. 本站所有資源如無(wú)特殊說(shuō)明,都需要本地電腦安裝OFFICE2007和PDF閱讀器。圖紙軟件為CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.壓縮文件請(qǐng)下載最新的WinRAR軟件解壓。
- 2. 本站的文檔不包含任何第三方提供的附件圖紙等,如果需要附件,請(qǐng)聯(lián)系上傳者。文件的所有權(quán)益歸上傳用戶(hù)所有。
- 3. 本站RAR壓縮包中若帶圖紙,網(wǎng)頁(yè)內(nèi)容里面會(huì)有圖紙預(yù)覽,若沒(méi)有圖紙預(yù)覽就沒(méi)有圖紙。
- 4. 未經(jīng)權(quán)益所有人同意不得將文件中的內(nèi)容挪作商業(yè)或盈利用途。
- 5. 眾賞文庫(kù)僅提供信息存儲(chǔ)空間,僅對(duì)用戶(hù)上傳內(nèi)容的表現(xiàn)方式做保護(hù)處理,對(duì)用戶(hù)上傳分享的文檔內(nèi)容本身不做任何修改或編輯,并不能對(duì)任何下載內(nèi)容負(fù)責(zé)。
- 6. 下載文件中如有侵權(quán)或不適當(dāng)內(nèi)容,請(qǐng)與我們聯(lián)系,我們立即糾正。
- 7. 本站不保證下載資源的準(zhǔn)確性、安全性和完整性, 同時(shí)也不承擔(dān)用戶(hù)因使用這些下載資源對(duì)自己和他人造成任何形式的傷害或損失。
最新文檔
- 國(guó)際貨幣和金融安排現(xiàn)狀與未來(lái)【外文翻譯】
- 金融學(xué)專(zhuān)業(yè)外文翻譯---行為金融學(xué)
- 金融學(xué)專(zhuān)業(yè)外文翻譯----金融危機(jī)蔓延與救援
- 金融學(xué)外文翻譯
- 金融學(xué)專(zhuān)業(yè)外文翻譯----金融服務(wù)外包現(xiàn)象分類(lèi)
- 貨幣金融學(xué)題庫(kù)
- 《貨幣金融學(xué)》課件
- 貨幣金融學(xué)答案
- 貨幣金融學(xué)試卷
- 貨幣金融學(xué)試題
- 金融學(xué)專(zhuān)業(yè)外文翻譯-----非正規(guī)與正規(guī)的轉(zhuǎn)帳金融服務(wù)或金融犯罪
- 貨幣金融、金融學(xué)試題2份
- 金融學(xué)外文翻譯---金融體系的比較
- 金融學(xué)專(zhuān)業(yè)國(guó)際金融課程教學(xué)大綱
- 金融學(xué)外文翻譯---金融體系的比較
- 《貨幣金融學(xué)》教學(xué)課件
- 《金融學(xué)外文翻譯》word版
- 貨幣金融學(xué)試題、答案
- 貨幣金融學(xué)章節(jié)習(xí)題
- 貨幣金融學(xué)考試重點(diǎn)
評(píng)論
0/150
提交評(píng)論