版權(quán)說明:本文檔由用戶提供并上傳,收益歸屬內(nèi)容提供方,若內(nèi)容存在侵權(quán),請進行舉報或認領(lǐng)
文檔簡介
1、<p><b> 外文翻譯</b></p><p><b> 原文</b></p><p> Trade,Growth,and the Environment</p><p> Material Source: Journal of Economic Literature,</p><
2、p> Vol.42,No.1,(Mar,2004)pp.7-71</p><p> Author: Brian R. Copeland and M. Scott Taylor</p><p> 3. Trade Liberalization and the Environment </p><p> We now turn to the impact
3、of international trade on the environment. We draw the usual distinction between trade and growth: trade liberalization changes relative goods prices by opening up the economy to increased foreign competition, while grow
4、th increases endowments or improves technology at given external prices. </p><p> While this distinction is clear, it may not always be accurate. There is empirical evidence that trade liberalization also s
5、timulates economic growth, and at a theoretical level, trade can alter the rate of growth if it spurs innovation or factor accumulation. In addition, trade may also pave the way for labor and capital mobility and technol
6、ogy transfer. Hence, trade can set in motion forces that shift the production. </p><p> We first examine the effects of trade on the environment in a small open economy facing fixed world prices to emphasiz
7、e three major points. First, the effect of trade liberalization on the environment depends on a country's comparative advantage, which in turn depends on country characteristics. There is no reason to expect trade to
8、 have the same effect on all countries. Second, the effects of trade on the environment depend on whether environmental policy is rigid or instead responsive to chang</p><p> Trade Frictions. For modeling p
9、urposes, we need to be specific about the trade barriers that are being reduced. Some trade barriers (such as tariffs) generate revenue; others, such as distance, generate productive activities such as transportation to
10、overcome them; and yet others, such as bureaucratic delays and regulations simply create trading costs. We don't want to focus on the details of trade policy, but simply capture the effects of increased opportunities
11、 to trade. To do so we assume the</p><p> With iceberg costs, an importer who wants to receive one unit of X from the foreign country has to ship 1+ units because is lost in transport. Trade therefore cons
12、umes real resources, and the magnitude of trade frictions increase as rises. </p><p> Trading costs drive a wedge between the domestic and foreign price of a good. As before let p denote the world price of
13、 X, then the domestic price of X for an importing country is: </p><p><b> (24)</b></p><p> Conversely, if Home exports X, then to deliver a unit of X to a foreign market (where the
14、 price is p), a home exporter must send 1+ units, which are acquired locally at the domestic price. Hence the domestic price is lower than the foreign price: </p><p><b> (25)</b></p><
15、p> It is convenient for us to use to refer to the domestic price, but the reader should keep in mind that whether this price is above or below the world price depends on the country's comparative advantage. </
16、p><p> 3.1 Rigid Policy </p><p> Fixed Emission Intensities. The effects of trade liberalization on the environment depend on the environmental policy regime. We start with a simple case where go
17、vernment policy holds the emission intensity of production fixed. This scenario is instructive because it simplifies the analysis by ruling out a technique effect, and may be a realistic approximation of policy in many c
18、ountries (at least in the short run) because much pollution regulation tends to target emissions intensities, rather t</p><p> Consider a country importing the dirty good X. The domestic price is initially
19、above the world price, and as trade barriers fall, the domestic relative price of X falls. As with growth, we can decompose the effects of trade liberalization into scale, composition and technique effects. This is illus
20、trated in figure 3. The production frontier (for a given emission intensity) is depicted in the top half of the diagram, and pollution is measured as a function of X in the bottom half. Starting with p</p><p&g
21、t; The scale effect is positive and tends to increase pollution. Trade increases production efficiency (measured at world prices), and this leads to more output, and hence more pollution. The composition effect is negat
22、ive, because protection is being removed from the polluting good, inducing producers to shift towards the clean good. In our simple model where only one good pollutes, the composition effect always dominates the scale ef
23、fect, because trade liberalization has an unambiguous effect on </p><p> If instead home exports X, then trade liberalization raises . Producers shift along the production frontier towards the dirty good. T
24、his both increases the scale of production and shifts the composition of output towards the polluting good: both the scale and composition effects reinforce each other and lead to an increase in pollution. </p>&l
25、t;p> In summary, with fixed emission intensities, the composition effect is critical in determining the effects of trade liberalization. Moreover, the sign of the composition effect is ultimately determined by a coun
26、try's comparative advantage. If a country has a comparative advantage in clean industries, then clean industries expand with trade; and conversely, if it has a comparative advantage in polluting industries, then dirt
27、y industries expand with trade. </p><p> Fixed Emission Permits. Now suppose the government uses a marketable emission permit system to regulate pollution, and that it does not adjust the supply of permit
28、s in response to changes in the trade regime. Earlier, we noted the equivalence of permit and tax systems as a method of implementing the first best. But if we hold policy instruments fixed in the face of shocks to the e
29、conomy, this equivalence breaks down.</p><p><b> 譯文</b></p><p><b> 貿(mào)易增長與環(huán)境</b></p><p> 資料來源: 經(jīng)濟文學期刊,42卷.第一章(2004.5)7-71頁</p><p> 作者:Brian R.
30、 Copeland and M. Scott Taylor</p><p> 3.貿(mào)易自由化和環(huán)境</p><p> 現(xiàn)在我們來看國際貿(mào)易對環(huán)境因素的影響。我們用一般貿(mào)易理論來區(qū)分貿(mào)易和發(fā)展;也就是說,貿(mào)易自由化的變化是由于開放經(jīng)濟改變了商品的價格進而增加了國外競爭力,同時增加了捐助或提升了技術(shù)的外部價格。</p><p> 雖然這區(qū)別非常明顯,但不可能很準確
31、。有證據(jù)說明貿(mào)易自由化也刺激了經(jīng)濟增長;從理論層面說,貿(mào)易自由化刺激了創(chuàng)新或增加了要素積累改變了貿(mào)易的增長速度。再者,貿(mào)易也可以鋪平道路或回歸于勞動、資本流動和技術(shù)轉(zhuǎn)讓。因此,貿(mào)易也能產(chǎn)生力量推動生產(chǎn)邊界轉(zhuǎn)移。</p><p> 我們首先研究在小型開放經(jīng)濟里貿(mào)易對環(huán)境的影響。面臨的固定價格強調(diào)了三個主要觀點。第一,貿(mào)易自由化對環(huán)境的影響根據(jù)一個國家的比較優(yōu)勢,而這也取決于國家的特征。沒有理由去期待所有國家會產(chǎn)生
32、相同的環(huán)境影響。第二,貿(mào)易的環(huán)境效應取決于政策是否僵化或者引起的新的貿(mào)易體制和經(jīng)濟情況能否適應經(jīng)濟環(huán)境的變化。最后,貿(mào)易自由化的福利對一個國家的比較優(yōu)勢和它的政策、政權(quán)影響都很敏感。</p><p> 我們從一個2區(qū)模型來了解兩個主要的假設(shè),與國家特征相聯(lián)系從而得出環(huán)保成果:污染避難所的假說和要素稟賦論的假說。這就規(guī)定的審查階段我們回顧實證的工作。</p><p> 貿(mào)易摩擦。我們需要
33、具體列出在我們的模型當中正在被減少的貿(mào)易壁壘這是建模的目的。有很多不同類型的貿(mào)易壁壘。一些(如關(guān)稅)產(chǎn)生收入;其他國家,像距離產(chǎn)生的生產(chǎn)活動,例如交通運輸,必須克服它們;另一些,如官僚主義的拖延和法規(guī)簡單的創(chuàng)造了貿(mào)易成本。就這一點而言,我們不想集中關(guān)注于貿(mào)易政策的細節(jié),而以一種簡單的方式去抓住貿(mào)易影響帶來的更多機會。為此,我們假設(shè)國家與國家之間有些貿(mào)易摩擦。我們采用了貿(mào)易成本的“冰山”模型。</p><p>
34、那就是,一個進口商想要從外國收到一個單位的X必須裝運單位因為消失在運輸中。貿(mào)易因此消耗真正的資源,貿(mào)易摩擦會以倍的增加。交易成本驅(qū)使國內(nèi)和國外價格在一個協(xié)調(diào)的邊緣。讓P代表世界價格X,然后國內(nèi)價格為X進口國就是:</p><p> 反之,如果國內(nèi)出口?,然后出口提供一單位?去國外市場?國外市場價格為P),國內(nèi)出口商必須發(fā)出1+?單位,在當?shù)孬@得的國內(nèi)價格為。因此國內(nèi)價格低于國外價格:</p>&l
35、t;p> 這會方便我們使用參考國內(nèi)價格,但是讀者必須保持清醒的頭腦就是價格高于或低于世界價格取決于國家的比較優(yōu)勢。</p><p><b> 3.1嚴格的政策</b></p><p> 固定的排放程度。貿(mào)易自由化對環(huán)境的影響取決于環(huán)境政策。我們從一個簡單的分析開始,政府政策是持有固定的生產(chǎn)排放強度。這個內(nèi)容是有啟發(fā)的,因為它簡化了分析,排除了技術(shù)的影響,可
36、能在很多國家是接近最真實的相似政策(至少在短期內(nèi))因為污染條例的規(guī)定傾向于目標強度的排放,而不是總的排放量。并且,這種條例包括了無污染的特殊條例規(guī)定。</p><p> 首先,思考一個國家進口了骯臟物品?,國內(nèi)價格最初高于世界價格,以及隨著貿(mào)易摩擦的下降,國內(nèi)相對價格?也下降。隨著經(jīng)濟的增長,我們可以將貿(mào)易自由化的影響分解成規(guī)模效應,結(jié)構(gòu)效應和技術(shù)效應。具體見圖?,生產(chǎn)邊界(對于給定的排放強度)圖中所示為圖的上
37、半部分,污染的測量以?分界在底部的下一半。生產(chǎn)商的價格為在A點,貿(mào)易自由化減少了國內(nèi)生產(chǎn)廠商的價格X到點,產(chǎn)量從A點轉(zhuǎn)移到C點,污染從Z0下降到了Z2。如果我們測量產(chǎn)量的規(guī)模,國際市場世界價格為p,然后假設(shè)沿著AB虛線向下移動(斜率為p)保持規(guī)模經(jīng)濟不變。這個污染程度的變化我們可以分解成結(jié)構(gòu)效應(A到B),它降低了污染使它從Z0到Z1,規(guī)模效應(B到C),它使污染程度從Z1上升到了Z2。如上所述,技術(shù)效應在這個例子中沒有影響假設(shè)。<
38、;/p><p> 規(guī)模效應是積極的,會增加污染。貿(mào)易增加了生產(chǎn)效率(以世界價格為準),這將導致更多的產(chǎn)出,因此導致更多的污染。結(jié)構(gòu)效應的影響是否定的,因為保護主義已被從污染商品中刪除,誘導生產(chǎn)商轉(zhuǎn)移到清潔商品。在我們簡單模型中,其中只有一種商品的污染,結(jié)構(gòu)效應總是支配著規(guī)模效應,因為貿(mào)易自由化明確影響著污染產(chǎn)品的輸出。如果經(jīng)濟在清潔商品中具有比較優(yōu)勢,在這個例子中,貿(mào)易對環(huán)境的影響是有利的。</p>
39、<p> 相反,如果國內(nèi)出口X,那么貿(mào)易自由化將增長。生產(chǎn)者沿著生產(chǎn)邊界轉(zhuǎn)向骯臟物品。這既增加了生產(chǎn)的規(guī)模也使產(chǎn)品的構(gòu)成轉(zhuǎn)向了污染商品,規(guī)模效應和結(jié)構(gòu)效應相輔相成,并引起污染的增加。 </p><p> 總之,在固定排放強度中,結(jié)構(gòu)效應在確定貿(mào)易自由化影響中是至關(guān)重要的,此外,結(jié)構(gòu)效應的最終決定是根據(jù)國家的比較優(yōu)勢,如果一個國家在干凈的行業(yè)擁有優(yōu)勢,那么清潔產(chǎn)業(yè)隨著貿(mào)易擴大;相反,如果它在污染行業(yè)擁
溫馨提示
- 1. 本站所有資源如無特殊說明,都需要本地電腦安裝OFFICE2007和PDF閱讀器。圖紙軟件為CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.壓縮文件請下載最新的WinRAR軟件解壓。
- 2. 本站的文檔不包含任何第三方提供的附件圖紙等,如果需要附件,請聯(lián)系上傳者。文件的所有權(quán)益歸上傳用戶所有。
- 3. 本站RAR壓縮包中若帶圖紙,網(wǎng)頁內(nèi)容里面會有圖紙預覽,若沒有圖紙預覽就沒有圖紙。
- 4. 未經(jīng)權(quán)益所有人同意不得將文件中的內(nèi)容挪作商業(yè)或盈利用途。
- 5. 眾賞文庫僅提供信息存儲空間,僅對用戶上傳內(nèi)容的表現(xiàn)方式做保護處理,對用戶上傳分享的文檔內(nèi)容本身不做任何修改或編輯,并不能對任何下載內(nèi)容負責。
- 6. 下載文件中如有侵權(quán)或不適當內(nèi)容,請與我們聯(lián)系,我們立即糾正。
- 7. 本站不保證下載資源的準確性、安全性和完整性, 同時也不承擔用戶因使用這些下載資源對自己和他人造成任何形式的傷害或損失。
最新文檔
- 貿(mào)易結(jié)構(gòu)與經(jīng)濟增長【外文翻譯】
- 貿(mào)易、發(fā)展與環(huán)境【外文翻譯】
- 服務(wù)貿(mào)易和增長【外文翻譯】
- 機構(gòu)、貿(mào)易及增長【外文翻譯】
- 服務(wù)貿(mào)易的開放度與經(jīng)濟增長【外文翻譯】
- 環(huán)境貿(mào)易措施【外文翻譯】
- 貿(mào)易與環(huán)境【外文翻譯】
- 貿(mào)易量與貿(mào)易政策對經(jīng)濟增長的分析【外文翻譯】
- 貿(mào)易開放與增長究竟有沒有聯(lián)系?【外文翻譯】
- 南北貿(mào)易與環(huán)境【外文翻譯】
- 出口與經(jīng)濟增長【外文翻譯】
- 經(jīng)濟與貿(mào)易外文翻譯
- 環(huán)境規(guī)制與國際貿(mào)易外文翻譯
- 環(huán)境規(guī)制與國際貿(mào)易【外文翻譯】
- 紡織品貿(mào)易和經(jīng)濟增長方式【外文翻譯】
- 貿(mào)易開放度與經(jīng)濟增長是出口導向型的增長還是進口導向型的增長【外文翻譯】
- 貿(mào)易和增長的實證研究政策建議在哪里?【外文翻譯】
- 美國出口貿(mào)易的發(fā)展特點及增長原因【外文翻譯】
- fdif與亞洲經(jīng)濟增長【外文翻譯】
- 中國的對外貿(mào)易環(huán)境【外文翻譯】
評論
0/150
提交評論